Friday, September 30, 2011

Externalities (Positive and Negative)















Externalities (Positive and Negative)

When making decisions, individuals and firms consider only those costs (and benefits) that it will directly bear. An activity will be considered worthwhile if the marginal benefit derived from the activity exceeds the marginal cost. However, for some activities, individuals or firms not directly involved in the activities receive benefits or bear costs related to those activities. These indirect benefits are called positive externalities, and these indirect costs are called negative externalities.

Example of a positive externality: Your neighbor decides to landscape their yard, and the resulting pleasant view increases your property values. Example of a negative externality: In manufacturing its products, a factory pollutes a river, reducing the number of fish and therefore the income of fishermen who also use the river. In neither case does the decision-maker have any incentive to take into account the benefits or costs accruing to others.

The requirement for economic efficiency is that MUA/MCA = MUB/MCB = MUC/MCC = etc. However, the values required for economic efficiency in both the short and long run are the societal MC and MR, which might not be the same as the individual MC and MR used in the decision-making process. As a result, economic efficiency suffers if either positive or negative externalities exist. If a positive externality exists, then the value of MU used in the decision-making process will understate societal MU, so societal MU/MC will not equal societal MU/MC for other goods and therefore economic efficiency will not prevail. Similarly, negative externalities result in an understatement of MC in the decision-making process, and again lead to an MU/MC ratio not equal to the comparable ratio for other goods and therefore to economic inefficiency.

If the entity that generates external costs or benefits, and the bearers of those costs and benefits, were to merge into a single firm, then there would be no problem because the firm’s decision-making would take all the costs and benefits into account. If all externalities are internalized, then the MU/MC ratio used in the firm’s decision-making process is the same as the societal MU/MC.

Thursday, September 29, 2011

Public Goods


















Public Goods

A private good is one for which each unit is consumed by only one individual or household. The key characteristics of a private good are excludability and rivalry. Excludability means that once a unit of the good is purchased by an individual, all other individuals are excluded from purchasing that particular unit of the good. Rivalry means that any purchase of a unit of the good means that there are less units available for all other purchasers.

A pure public good exhibits neither excludability nor rivalry. National defense is a pure public good. It is “consumed” by everyone, but this consumption does not reduce the amount available to everyone else. Many goods are neiter purely public nor purely private. A highway behaves like a public good when it is lightly used, but under heavy traffic it behaves more like a private good.

Market forces will not lead to economic efficiency for public goods, because of the free rider problem. The example given is ten wealthy families living on a lake, on which a mosquito problem exists. The cost of spraying the lake is sufficiently low that each family considers it worthwhile to spray the lake. If the ten families do not communicate, then each will independently decide to spray the lake. This is a gross misallocation of resources because the lake will be sprayed ten times when only once would have sufficed for all the families.

Alternately, one of the homeowners might observe another spraying the lake, and if asked to contribute to the cost, could claim to enjoy the mosquitoes. There is no way to deny the non-paying homeowner the benefit of the paying homeonwner’s expenditure. What’s more, it is unlikely that the lake will actually be sprayed, because each homeowner will wait for one of the others to pay the cost.

The solution to this problem is for all the homeowners to get together and agree to act collectively. However, this behavior will not arise from a free market. One of the main functions of government is to ensure the production of public goods which people want but which would not be produced in a pure market economy. Examples: Police and fire protection; national defense; pure research; roads; public parks. Not all people enjoy these goods equally, and tax structures are such that not all people pay for the equally, but these are generally matters of policy, not economics.

However, the government must attempt to produce an economically efficient allocation of resources to the production of public goods. In order to do so, it must attempt to calculate the marginal social benefit and marginal social cost of any given program, and attempt to equate the ratios of MSB/MSC for each program in which it engages. The benefits and costs must include estimates not only of the direct actions to be taken, but also the opportunity costs and wider changes resulting from the actions. For example, an immunization program not only reduces medical costs, but also decreases absences and therefore increases worker productivity. A university subsidy also increases worker productivity, but at the same time it decreases output because new students enrolling at the subsidized price would otherwise presumably have been workers.

Wednesday, September 28, 2011

LAFFER CURVE











Laffer’s argument is that if the income tax rate were 100%, nobody would be willing to work since all wages and salaries would go in taxes; government tax revenue would therefore be zero. As tax rates decreased, some people would begin to work and tax revenues would increase, to some maximum at some point; below that point, decreasing tax rates would begin to result in decreased revenues, again reaching zero when the tax rate is zero. Some tax rate X exists where maximum revenue is achieved. If the government is already taxing at this rate, any change, positive or negative will result in reduced revenues. Moreover, if the government is already taxing above this rate, an increase in tax rates will be accompanied by a decrease in revenues; the budget-balancing action in this case would be to reduce tax rates. Hence Reaganomics and ‘voodoo economics.’ If you believe in the Laffer curve, then any increase or decrease in the tax rate must be based on a good estimate of where the economy is currently positioned.

Causes and Effects of Inflation




Causes and Effects of Inflation

In the post-WWII period all major economies have experienced inflation, although the rate of inflation has varied widely both between nations and between time periods for a given nation. The persistence of inflation and the tendency for the rate of inflation to rise for substantial periods has resulted in a situation where great weight is given to the prevention of inflation, even at the expense of allowing a high rate of unemployment. Inflation is undesirable for two main reasons:

·         Inflation impairs the efficiency of the price mechanism and raises transaction costs because money becomes less reliable as a standard of value. In the presence of inflation it is difficult to know if a price increase on a given good represents an increase in the general price level, or an increase in the price of that good relative to other goods. In order to answer this question, it would be necessary to collect information on the current prices of many other goods. Similarly, the seller will have difficulty determining the relevant prices of factor inputs, substitute goods, etc.
·         Unanticipated inflation redistributes income and resources in a largely capricious manner. Inflation penalizes those with incomes that are fixed in money terms, and favors those whose money income reacts quickly to changes in the price level. The former group includes most pensioners, students, and many salary earners, while the latter group includes most wage and profit earners. Where household incomes include transfer payments from the government, it is possible to index payments to keep pace with inflation, but the more successfully this is done, the greater the inflationary bias in the economy. Unanticipated inflation also favors borrowers and penalizes lenders, because if the loan amount and interest payments are fixed in money terms, inflation results in the lender receiving less real value than expected—if the inflation continues, lenders will respond by charging higher interest rates to compensate. Finally, if tax brackets are assigned based on nonindexed money values, inflation can shift the boundary real income between tax brackets, which can result in a major unplanned reallocation of income from households to the government. Indexing taxes will prevent this outcome, but again, the more successfully taxes are indexed, the greater the inflationary bias in the economy.
·         A continued higher rate of domestic inflation than that which prevails in other nations will increase imports, reduce exports, and create problems for continued stable currency exchange rates.

In the presence of unanticipated inflation, the above effects are often capricious and unintended. Continued inflation will lead to an adjustment in behavior patterns which can mitigate the effects, but inflation can never be fully anticipated. Full anticipation would require not only full information on the aggregate rate of inflation, but also requires that every economic agent have information on all the relative price movements which affect their decisions.

Up to WWII most industrialized nations experienced periods of inflation cycling with periods of stable or falling prices. Occasional examples of high, sustained inflation can be found as a result of things like the Spanish gold discoveries of the fifteenth century and the German hyper-inflation of 1923, but these were isolated events with an easily identifiable cause. The sustained and near-continuous inflation experienced by all major economies subsequent to WWII has no historical precedent. The emergence of persistent, widespread inflation has led to a major re-examination of the theory of price determination. At the most basic level the proposed theories can be classified into ‘demand-pull’ and ‘cost-push’ models.

The demand-pull model, favored by Keynes, sees price increases as a consequence of excess demand for goods and services which exceed the capacity output of the economy. As real output cannot increase significantly beyond capacity output, excess demand ‘pulls up’ the prices of final goods and services. At the same time, as firms bid up the prices of factors of producion, money incomes rise. This approach has some problems. It cannot explain monetary factors which are clearly observed to be capable of causing inflation (eg, the Spanish gold discoveries), nor does it deal with the possibility that monetary factors could be used to combat inflation. It also regards wage and salary earners as passively reacting to changes in the price level by bargaining up their incomes. However, in the 1950s and 1960s, more centralized wage and salary bargaining became a feature of the major economies, and as a result a new school of thinking developed which elevated labor markets to a primary, causative role in the determination of the price level.

This new, ‘cost-push’ model sees price increases as a consequence of bargains struck in the factor (primarily labor) markets, which raise the production costs of employers, who then pass on higher costs in the form of higher prices. Most cost-push models incorporate the following elements:
-          Prices and costs are ‘administered’ rather than responsive to the market forces of demand and supply. With the exception of a few truly competitive markets (agricultural commodities, for example), most markets for final products have some strong anti-competitive elements, meaning that one or a small number of producers have an influential role in setting prices.
-          Similarly, labor markets are ‘administered’ in that wages and salaries are largely determined by bargains struck between employers and trade unions, rather than by market forces.
-          Final product prices are also ‘administered’ on the basis that firms set prices on a cost-plus basis, with prices reflecting the full cost of production plus some mark-up for profit. As a result, if costs rise, firms will attempt to pass on the higher costs to consumers, in the form of higher prices—so the whole economy is essentially on a cost-plus basis.
-          The purpose of trade unions is to bargain better pay for their members.
-          Labor represents the single largest factor market, by a wide margin.

Under such a system, bargaining over money wages and salaries is considered the primary ‘motor’ of inflation. Trade unions continually attempt to bargain for better wages and salaries. Sometimes, they are successful. When this happens, the factor costs of labor (the largest cost of production) increase, so firms pass this increase on to consumers in the form of higher prices. The increase in prices will erode the real value of the money increase in wages, which may then lead to further demands for wage increases. ‘Cost-push’ inflation originates with higher wage costs which then push up prices. Cost-push inflation is likely to occur in economies where wages and salaries are not flexible downwards, a feature of most modern economies. It has long been recognized that workers, trade unions, etc., will particularly resist any cut in money wages. That being so, firms, faced with lower demand for their products, may be reluctant to lower prices, because the ‘stickiness’ of wages would mean that the price cuts would mainly be at the expense of profits. Instead, the firms will lower output and therefore employment.

Where deficient demand may not cause prices to fall, excess demand will be reflected in higher wages and prices. In other words, the reaction of wages and prices is asymmetrical. If this is so, then a change in the distribution of demand, even given the same aggregate demand, could cause prices to rise. Inflation does not occur as a result of excess aggregate demand, but rather as the result of excess demand in particular markets and the failure of prices to fall in particular demand-deficient markets. In addition, price increases in particular markets are likely to trigger ‘spill-over’ or ‘linkage’ effects in other markets. For exampe, if wage agreements are interlinked so that trade unions negotiate similar wage increases for everyone they represent, then ‘bidding up’ of wages in one sector will encourage workers in other sectors to demand raises as well.

Cost-push inflation can only occur in the presence of a permissive monetary policy which allows the continued expansion of the money supply. Higher wages which result in higher prices must raise the money value of output, unless offset by an accompanying reduction in output and employment. If the money supply is fixed, it would be necessary for the velocity of circulation of money to rise to generate the higher level of monetary demand consistent with the higher money value of output. To sustain a continuing inflation, the velocity of circulation of money would have to increase continuously. As the velocity of circulation is heavily influenced by institutional arrangements and existing habits, it is unlikely to be able to change quickly enough to sustain much inflation.

In short, if faced with an increase in money wages, the monetary authorities can either hold the money supply constant or allow it to increase but at a rate lower than the rate of increase of money wages, with the result of a fall in output and employment but stable prices, or they can allow the money supply to increase to allow a sufficient level of monetary demand to sustain the same output at higher prices.

There are two additional possible sources for cost-push inflation: Imports and expectations. Imported inflation occurs when trade or other factors cause the prices of imported goods to rise, particularly when demand for those goods is relatively price inelastic; not only do consumers pay mor directly for the imported goods, but because imported factor inputs are now more expensive, inflation will accelerate through the entire economy, as in the 1970s oil crisis. Expectations-based inflation is a relatively recent concept. Economic models generally treat expectations one of three ways:
·         Expectations are static – people always expect the current situation to continue;
·         Expectations are adaptive – people’s expectations change over time to adjust to the situation;
·         Expectations are rational – people base their expectations on the same information as is available to policy makers.

The favorite example of rational expectations is the stock market. If you read in the newspaper that IBM is going to have a good year, there is no point rushing to buy the stock as a result, because everyone else has already read the newspaper article and market trading has already adjusted the price of IBM stock to account for the news. Nor is there any point taking advice from your stockbroker, as anything the stockbroker knows is already accounted for by the market prices of stocks. The only information which has not already been accounted for in the stock prices is insider information, but trading based on insider information is illegal. The theory incorporating rational expectations is called the Efficient Market Hypothesis. Expectations affect the inflation rate to the extent that firms and individuals do business in the expectation of future benefits or costs. If you agree to purchase goods for future delivery, you must agree on a price today. The price which you are willing to pay will depend on your expectations of the future value of the goods to be delivered, which depends on your expectations regarding inflation. If you have agreed to a deal at some specified price and date in the future, you have in effect established a part of what the price level will be on that future date.

Anti-Inflationary Policies

The distinction between demand-pull and cost-push inflation is very important for regulatory purposes. If inflation is considered cost-push in origin, arising from institutional labor agreements, then the only way to change the rate of inflation is to change the institutional framework within which these agreements are made. If expectations are the cause of inflation, then in the long run those expectations must be changed if inflation is to be curbed. Both Keynesian and monetarist approacues suggest that inflation should be combated by reducing demand, but they disagree on how: Keynesians would reduce demand through fiscal policy (increase taxes / decrease government expenditure), monetarists through monetary policy (restrict the money supply). This having been said, it is in practice quite difficult to determine the cause of inflation.

Worker productivity (and hence potential output) increases with time. If produtivity is increasing by 2% per year, then a 2% money wage increase per year will be consistent with price stability. In other words, price stability results when D(Money Wages)+D(Worker Productivity)= D(Price Level). As a result, the Phillips Curve, which is normally shown as inflation vs. unemployment, can also be shown as change in money wages vs. unemployment.

One weakness of the Phillips Curve is that it is possible to interpret the empirical results as showing either a demand-pull or a cost-push explanation of inflation. As a demand-pull explanation: As unemployment decreases, excess demand for labor increases, and vice versa, in a stable and predictable fashion. The higher the excess demand for labor, the greater the rate of increase of money wages, and vice versa, again in a stable and predictable fashion. As a result, there is a stable and predictable inverse relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages. As a cost-push explanation: At high levels of unemployment, trade unions and employee groups would be less likely to demand money wage increases because the reality of layoffs and unemployment would be more visible. As unemployment decreases, these same groups would become steadily more militant, and at the same time firms would be more willing to allow costs to rise and to pass on these additional costs in the form of prices, since at low unemployment (in a ‘hot’ economy) their sales are less likely to suffer as a result of the price increases.

While empirical evidence confirms the validity of the Phillips Curve in the short run, it is not at all clear if it is valid in the long run. It has been suggested that the trade-off between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages is a transitory phenomenon resulting from the failure of expectations to adjust immediately to price changes. Once expectations adjust to the new price level, according to this theory, the trade-off effect between inflation and unemployment disappears entirely. This analysis has gained credibility in recent years because of the evident breakdown in the historical relationship between the price level and the unemployment rate. The 1970s and early 1980s witnessed ‘stagflation’ – a sustained simultaneous increase in both the rate of inflation and the rate of unemployment. Advocates of the Phillips Curve argued that the curve had simply shifted upwards on an ongoing basis because of expectations and exogenous events.

Monetarists have a more fundamental objection to the Phillips Curve. They argue that labor is concerned with the rate of change of real wages, rather than money wages. If this is so, a tradeoff between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages will only exist when labor expectations are that the rate of inflation should be zero or close to it. As soon as labor expects to see a noteworthy rate of inflation, the short run relationship between unemployment and money wages will shift to the right, with the magnitude of the shift depending on how high the inflation rate is expected to be. In the long run, therefore, there is no tradeoff between unemployment and inflation. By this analysis, policy makers are not able to select combinations of unemployment and inflation rates; in fact, macroeconomic policy is unable to affect the long run rate of employment at all. In the long run, only the rate of inflation can be controlled and therefore the policy maker should choose a zero rate of inflation.

Milton Friedman, the leading monetarist, postulates a ‘natural rate of unemployment’ which is similar to the previously-considered full employment rate of unemployment. Friedman suggests that the actual rate of unemployment can only be reduced below the ‘natural’ rate in the short term by the creation of inflation beyond expectations, and it can only be held below the ‘natural’ rate by continuing to accelerate inflation so that there is always a ‘gap’ between expected inflation and actual inflation. To combat unemployment in the long run, the ‘natural’ rate must be reduced, and this has nothing to do with macroeconomic policy. The ‘natural’ rate of unemployment depends on factors such as the efficiency of information flow in the job market, the rate of structural change in the economy, the costs of undertaking additional worker training, etc.

Monetarists consider that the demand for money is a stable function of a number of variables such as the level of income, the expected rate of return on investments, and the rate of change in prices. This implies that the velocity of circulation of money (V) will be quite stable. Keynesians believe that changes in V may offset and frustrate monetary policy; for example, in a depression, increases in the money supply will find themselves largely falling into precautionary and speculative balances, so that V falls and no overall change is seen to the level of aggregate demand.

Monetarists consider that the demand for and supply of money are largely independent of each other; the supply of money is determined exogenously by the regulatory authorities. It follows that given a stable demand function for money, exogenous changes to the money supply will result in predictable changes to aggregate demand and therefore inflation rates. Modern Keynesians believe that the money supply may be determined, at least in part, endogenously; it may be responsive to economic variables. For example, if the level of money wages rises due to union bargaining, the commercial banks and/or central money authority may expand the money supply to ‘underwrite’ these changes—in effect the money supply has responded to a change in the price level.

Keynesians further suggest that the central monetary authority may be unable to control the money supply effectively. The commercial banks may be able to frustrate the desires of the regulatory authority by finding effective substitutes for money (such as credit card balances), or by finding more efficient ways to use money (income tax deducted at source, for example, reduces the demand for money and therefore increases the ability to use what money exists).

When it all comes down, monetarists maintain that changes in the money supply have been the chief cause of substantial fluctuations in national income/output, causing both major inflations and major recessions. The monetarist view is that monetary policy can have a major impact on the level of real income and employment in the economy. Therefore, the monetarists maintain, monetary policy should follow an automatic rule, allowing an annual change in money supply to match the long-run growth rate of the economy. As a result, whenever the economy is operating at less than its potential, the overly-large money supply will fuel additional output and income; conversely, whenever excess demand exists beyond potential output, the overly-restricted money supply will ‘put on the brakes’ and return the economy to Q. Government attempts to expand or contract the money supply during the business cycle will simply result in heightened oscillations.

The following observations are from empirical evidence and would be acceptable to nearly all economists:
1.        There has never been any major inflation occurring without an accompanying substantial increase in the money supply.
2.        There has never been a substantial increase in the money supply which has not been accompanied by a major inflation.
3.        Given 1 and 2, a high rate of inflation cannot be sustained unless the money supply is expanded.

In examples of major inflation, such as Germany in 1923, America in the 1970s, or the sustained high rates of inflation currently observed in Latin American nations, the monetarist explanation fits empirical data better than Keynesian theory. However, in milder inflations, it can be argued that changes in the money supply are permissive but not causal.

In terms of the circular flow of income, if a large trade union is successful in negotiating a wage increase, then the firms in that industry will charge higher prices to compensate and money national output will rise. However, all output eventually accrues as income to resource owners. As a result, the total money income of all resource owners will rise. Given that all resource owners have some marginal propensity to hold money for precautionary and transactional purposes, a net increase to the total demand for money will occur. If the money supply is held constant by the regulatory authorities, then the amount of money available for speculative purposes will fall. In order to ensure that households and businesses are content to hold this reduced amount of speculative money, interest rates must rise. However, this will discourage investment, resulting in a fall of aggregate demand. In short, unless there is an increase in the money supply, then the process of passing on higher costs in the form of higher prices cannot be sustained indefinitely without a serious adverse effect on aggregate demand and consequent unemployment. While it is true that sustained inflation is impossible in the face of a sustained and determined attempt to restrain the money supply, this attempt will also generate undesirable consequences for the economy.

Keynesians and monetarists both accept that if the money supply does not increase, there will be higher unemployment. They disagree on the amount and duration of unemployment which would be necessary to contain inflation, and in their assessment of the long-term benfits as compared to the short-term costs of a restrictive monetary policy. Keynesians would argue that modern governments have a strong responsibility for ensuring full employment; a departure from full employment would involve heavy economic, social and political costs in the short term which must be weighed more heavily than possible long-term benefits. Monetarists, on the other hand, believe that such output and employment losses are temporary phenomena that the long-term benefit of price stability more than makes up for. Moreover, monetarists believe that any attempt to increase employment beyond its ‘natural’ rate will be self-defeating and simply result in more costly problems in the long run. In fact, monetarists would argue that price stability will reduce unemployment in the long run, since price stability improves the efficiency of markets, including the labor market

Properties of the Phillips Curve











Properties of the Phillips Curve

The Phillips Curve has another important property: It is not linear. Its curvature suggests that the nature of the trade-off between inflation and unemployment depends on where the economy currently falls on the curve. At high rates of unemployment, the curve is relatively flat: It takes a large increase in unemployment to effect a small increase in inflation. At lower rates of unemployment, a small change in unemployment will result in a much larger change in inflation.

This can be explained as follows: If the initial condition is high unemployment, then most labor markets will be characterized by excess supply and very few by excess demand. If unemployment increases, the excess demand in those few markets will be reduced, so those few firms will still increase their prices but not by as much as they would have otherwise. However, the downward rigidity of the labor markets already experiencing excess supply will be such that the firms operating in those markets will not change their prices. As a result, the change in the rate of inflation will be small. However, if the initial condition is very low unemployment, most labor markets will be characterized by excess demand and very few by excess supply. If unemployment increases, the upward pressure on wages will be decreased, perhaps sharply in those cases where the initial excess demand was severe. Since very few labor markets were in excess supply conditions, most firms will still expect an increase in labor costs, but less (possibly much less) than previously. As a result, price increases for the majority of firms will be less than they would have been, and there will be some firms which might otherwise have set very sharp price increases who no longer need to do so. The reduction in the rate of incrase of the average price level will be very noticeable.

The existence of a Phillips Curve causes a problem for government policymakers. A choice must be made between the evils of unemployment and of inflation. Policy tools that affect aggregate demand cannot be used to fight inflation and unemployment at the same time. If aggregate demand is controlled to achieve full employment, some inflation will generally result. If aggregate demand is controlled to eliminate inflation, high unemployment will generally result.

Inflationary Bias


Inflationary Bias

The labor market is quantitatively the most important factor of production, since it accounts for roughly two-thirds of all income payments by firms. The ‘labor market’ is in fact many different markets, as workers are specialized in many different skills. At any given time, there will probably be some skills that have excess demand while other skills have excess supply. All these markets operate imperfectly, in the sense that wages do not adjust immediately to equate supply and demand. This is particularly evident in many markets where there is excess supply; wage rates are observed not to respond to the downward pressure. Wage rates appear to be ‘sticky’ in the face of high unemployment.

Many reasons are given for this observation. One is that in many labor markets, wages are determined by collective bargaining between unions and management, sometimes for an entire industry. The political nature of union decision-making is such that a reduction in wages is exceedingly difficult to obtain, regardless of economic circumstances. A reduction in wages makes everyone somewhat worse off. However, a failure to reduce wages makes certain people (those laid off) much worse off, to the benefit of others (those who keep their jobs). If the economic downturn is anything short of catastrophic, less than half the workers are likely to be laid off. If the workers have a good idea who will be axed, then the majority of workers, voting in their own self-interest, will elect to keep their current wages. In addition, those workers with the most seniority are the least likely to be laid off, therefore the most likely to oppose wage reductions—but this group of people are also likely to hold the most influential positions within the union. Another explanation is that given that the government will pay unemployment benefits for a while, a typical worker may be better off accepting work at a high wage in the knowledge that there will be occasional layoffs, than accepting work at a lower wage that continues indefinitely.

This rigidity does not occur in the upwards direction. Workers are always generally happy to accept more money. As discussed previously, full employment does not mean zero unemployment. It is still possible (even likely) that under full employment, some labor markets will have excess demand while others will have excess supply. In markets with excess demand, wages can be expected to rise relatively quickly, but in markets with excess supply, wages will only fall slowly, if at all. Firms which face excess demand for labor will expect their costs to rise and will therefore set higher prices. However, firms which face excess supply of labor will not have a reasonable expectation of falling costs, and will therefore leave prices unchanged. This will result in an increase in the average price level.

If unemployment rates are high enough, the downward pressure on wages will be sufficient to overcome downward wage rigidity and wages and prices will fall. There have been very few occasions where this has occurred; the most striking example is the Great Depression in the 1930s, where, in the face of extremely high unemployment rates, the inflation rate was negative for several years on many countries.

Output and Inflation....Phillips Curve...


Output and Inflation

Aggregate demand determines the actual output of goods and services produced. Given a fixed potential output for any short-term period, aggregate demand will thus determine the unemployment rate. In the simple model used above, when aggregate demand exceeds potential output, an inflationary gap exists and the price level rises. However, in the real world, inflation occurs at or below full employment.

The inflation rate for a given time period is the per year change in price level: INFT = (PT+1-PT)/PT. The price level represents the overall price of all goods and services taken together. The most commonly cited measure of the average price level is the Consumer Price Index (CPI). This provides an index of typical consumer products purchased by average households. However, it does not take into account the roughly one-third of total output represented by investment expenditure. The price level index which includes all goods and services in the economy is called the GDP deflator.

Most firms set their prices based on the anticipated costs of production and the anticipated demand for the goods and services produced. These expectations are based on past performance, economic indicators, and the thought processes of managers. The most recent level of aggregate demand is one of the key factors determining these expectations. The higher aggregate demand, the higher the firm’s own recent demand is likely to have been, and the higher its expectations of future demand. In addition, the higher the aggregate demand, the higher the firm’s expectations about the cost of labor, materials and other factor inputs. As a result, the higher recent aggregate demand has been, the higher a firm is likely to set its prices. If all firms operate in this fashion, then the rate of increase of the price level will be directly and positively related to the level of aggregate demand.

In any short run period, therefore, aggregate demand will influence both the unemployment rate and the inflation rate. As a result, there will be an implied relationship between unemployment and inflation. For each possible level of aggregate demand, there will be corresponding rate of unemployment and of inflation. The graph of unemployment against inflation for a varying level of aggregate demand in the short run is called a Phillps Curve:










In the real world, the constraint that Y cannot exceed Q is somewhat relaxed, because of the way we have defined full employment. Facing demand exceeding Q, some fatories and workers can work overtime and the average frictional and structural rates of unemployment will fall because there are so many unfilled vacancies.  Thus the economy in the short run can ‘squeeze’ some extra production out of its resources. However, the cost of this economic ‘boom’ is that factor prices will rise and consequently the price level will rise at a rate higher than normal. This is represented by the increasing slope of the Phillips Curve as unemployment goes above UF.

One might expect inflation at full employment to be zero, because at over-full employment, scarcity of factors of production will lead to rising demand and thus rising prices; at under-full employment, abundance of factors of production will lead to reduced demand and thus reduced prices; and at exact full employment, demand and supply will be in equilibrium, resulting in stable prices. Empirically, however, the position of the Phillips Curve has been such that some positive rate of inflation occurs at the full emploment rate of unemployment. This is caled the inflationary bias.

Monday, September 26, 2011




INTRODUCTION
 “All such institutions and organistions, which provide people with the means to work and earn an income, are collectively called an Economy.
Basic activities of an Economy.
1.         Production refers to creation of utility or increasing the value of commodities already            produced.
2.         Consumption is using up of goods and services to satisfy haman want directly.
3.         Capital Formation/Investment refers to addition to the capital stock of an economy.
Economic Problem :- It is basically problem of making choices in the use of scarce resoures  for satisfaction of choice arises due to scarcity of resources and their alternative uses, For an economy Economic problem is the problem of resource allocation or making choices in the allocation of scarce resources having alternative uses.
Causes of Economic Problem:
(i) Human wants are unlimited  (ii) resouces to satisfy wants are limited (iii) resources have alternative uses.
Central (Basic) Problem of an Economy Allocation of resourcesor making choices among alternative uses of scarce resources is the fundamental problem.
1.         What to produce and in  what quantity?
            It is the problem of choosing which commodities should be produced and in what quan        tity i.e. necessity goods or luxury goods.
2.         How to produce?
            It is problem of choosing method or technique of production of goods. i.e. Labour inten                    sive or Capital intensive.
3.         For whom to produce.
It refers to distribution of  factor income  among various factors of production since production is the result of combined efforts of factors of production i. e. Iand, labour, capital, enterprise.
DISTINCTION BETWEEN MARKET ECONOMY AND CENTRALLY PLANNED ECONOMY.
1-         Market Economy : An economy in which all economic activities are organised through the   market i.e. free interaction of buyers and sellers to affect purchase and sale of a commodity.                  (Price mechanism)
Central Problems of what, how and for whom to produce are solved by price-mechanism.
2.         Centrally Planned Economy :- It is one in which all important activities  are planned and decided by the central planning authority or the Govt.
Central Problems of what, how and for whom to produce are solved by the central authority known as planning commission appointed by the Govt.


Branch of Economics
1.         Micro economic theory  (also called Price Theory) deals with the allocation of resources which is decided by price mechanism.
2.         Macro-economic Theory deals with full employment of resources along with other aggregrates of economy i.e. national income, price level, national saving etc.
Production Possibility Frontier
It is a curve which depicts all possible combinations of two goods which an economy can produce with available technology and with full and efficient use of its given resources.
Assumption
1.         Resources are fixed.
2.         Resources are  fully & efficiently used.
3.         Technology does not change.
4.         Resources are not equally efficient in production of all goods.

Production Possibility Schedule
with MOC & MRT
Production  Possibilities
Wheat (w) (Lakh tonnes)
TanKs(T) (thousands)
MOC of Wheat
MRT= ∆ tanks/ ∆wheat
A
O
15
-
-
B
1
14
1(15-14)
1 W = 1 T
C
2
12
2(14-12)
1 W = 2 T
D
3
9
3
1 W = 3 T
E
4
5
4
1 W = 4 T
F
5
0
5
1 W = 5 T

By joining the different possibilities of production i.e. wheat on x-axis and tanks on y-axis production possibility curve is drawn.











1.         Every point on PP curve (A, B, C, D, E) reflects situation of full and efficient employment resources.
2.         Point Below PP curve reflects the silation of inefficient utilisation or under-utilisatiion of         resources. (Leftward shift)
3.         Point above PP curve indicates situation of growth of resources. (Rightward shift)

SHAPE OF PRODUCTION POSSIBLITY CURVE
1.         It slopes down from left to right because in a situation of full employment of resources production of one good can be increased only after sacrificing some quantity of other good.
            (1 W = 2 T............ ..............)
2.         The shape of PP curve is concave to the origin due to increasing marginal opportunity cost. It implies that for producing an additional unit of a good, sacrifice of units of other good goes on increasing.
(*)        PP curve could be a straight line if sacrifice of units of good is constant. MOC(MRT) is constant.
OPPORTUNITY COST :-  It is equal to the value of next best alternative forgone (scarificed)
Marginal opportunity cost :- It refers to the amount of other good which is sacrificed to produce an additional unit of the particular good.
Marginal Rate of Transformation : It is defined as the ratio of units of one good scarificed for production of an additional unit of other good.

                Unit of one good sacrificed                      ∆ tanks
MRT=  ------------------------------------------    =              -----------
            More units of other good produced             ∆ wheat
 
                       



Positive economic analysis :-
1.         It studies the actuals as “they are”
2.         It analyses the cause & effect relationship.
3.         Ethics of  economic decisions are not touched. i.e. INDIA is over-populated.
Normative economic analysis :
1.         It deals with things as they ought to be”
2.         It passes moral judgement.
3.         It deals with idealistic situation instead of actual situation i. e. Interest free loans should be given to the poor farmers.
Micro economics :- It is that part of economic theory which deals with the individual parts of the economic system such as individual households, individual firms or industries.
It is called price theory because it is concerned with the determination of price of individual commodities and factors.
Macro economics: - It is that part of economic theory which studies the economy in its totality or as a whole, dealing with aggregrates. such as ‘National income, aggregate employment, general price-level
It is also known as “Theory of income and employment because the subject-matter of macro-economics revolves around determination of the level of income & employment.

Saturday, September 24, 2011

Balance of Payments


     

                                                            Balance of Payments                                

Balance of Payment Account : A Balance of Payment Account is a systematic record of all economic transactions between residents of a country and the rest of the world carried out in a specific period of time.
Components of Balance of Payment Account :
1.     Export and import of goods. (visible items).
2.     Services rendered and received (invisible items).
3.      Unilateral transfers.
4.      Capital receipts and payments.
Balance of Trade : It is the difference between the money value of exports and imports of material goods.  (called visible items or merchandise).
Balance of Payment : It is the difference between a nation’s total payments of foreign countries and its total receipts from them.
Current Account of Balance of Payment : The current account is that account which records imports and exports of goods, services and unilateral transfers.
Capital Accounts of Balance of Payment : The capital accounts of BOP records all such  transactions between residents of a country and the rest of the world which cause a change in the assets or liability status of residents of a country or its government.
Components of Current Account :
(i)   Export and Import of goods (visible trade)
(ii)  Export and import of services- non factor and factor services (called invisible trade)
(iii) Unilateral transfers (transfer receipts/payments).
(iv)  Investment income (factor income from land, bonds, shares abroad).
Components of Capital Accounts :
(i)    Private transactions :
(ii)   Official transactions :
(iii)   Direct investment :
(iv)    Portfolio investment :
Autonomous Items in BOP : These refer to international economic transactions that take place due to some economic motives like profit maximisation.  Such transactions are independent of the state of country’s BOP.  These items are generally called ‘above the line items’ in BOP.
Accommodating items in BOP : These refer to transactions that take place because of other activity in BOP like government financing.
Deficit in BOP : It refers to current account of BOP.  If autonomous receipts are less than autonomous payments, the BOP is in deficit reflecting disequilibrium in BOP.

                                                Foreign Exchange Rate

Foreign Exchange means foreign currency.
Foreign Exchange Rate : The rate at which currency of one country can be exchanged for currency of another country is called the rate of Foreign Exchange.
Nominal Vs Real Exchange Rate
Nominal echange rate is price of foreign currency in terms of domestic currency.  Real exchange rate is the relative price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods.
Foreign Exchange Market : The market in which national currencies of various countries are
converted,exchanged or traded for one another is called foreign exchange market.
Spot Market : If the operation is of daily nature, it is called spot market or current market.  The
exchange rate that prevails in the  spot market for foreign exchange is called Spot Rate.
Forward Market :  A market in which foreign exchange is bought and sold for future delivery is
known as forward market.  Exchange rate that prevails in a forward contract for purchase or sale of foreign exchange is called Forward Rate.
Determination of Rate of Foreign Exchange
In a system of flexible exchange rate, the exchange rate of a currency is determined by forces of demand and supply of foreign exchange.  Expressed graphically, the intersection of demand and
the supply curves determines the equilibrium exchange rate and equilibrium quantity of foreign currency.
Sources of Demand for Foreign Exchange.
The following factors cause demand for foreign exchange.
(a)       To purchase goods and services by domestic residents from foreign countries.
(b)       To purchase financial assets.
(c)        To send gifts and grants abroad.
(d)       To undertake foreign tours etc.
There is inverse relationship between price of foreign exchange and demand for foreign exchange.   That is why demand curve for foreign exchange becomes downward sloping.
Sources of Supply of Foreign Exchange
(i)         When foreigners purchase home country’s goods and services through exports.
(ii)        When foreigners invest in bonds and equity shares of the home country.
(iii)       When Indian workers working abroad send their savings to families in India.
(iv)       When foreign tourists come to India.
There is a direct relationship between price of foreign exchange and supply of foreign exchange.
That is why supply curve is upward rising.
Equilibrium Exchange Rate : This is determined at a point where demand for and supply of foreign exchange are equal.  Graphically, intersection of demand and supply curves determine the equilibrium exchange rate of foreign currency.
                     

Quantity of US dollars
Fixed Exchange Rate System : Fixed exchange rate is the rate which is officially fixed by the
govt. or monetary authority and not determined by market forces.
Flexible (Floating) Exchange Rate System : The system in which rate of exchange is determined by forces of demand and supply in foreign exchange market.
NEER : Nominal Effective Exchange Rate : It is the measure of average relative strength of a given currency with respect to other currencies without eliminating the effect of price change.
REER: Real Effective Exchange Rate : It calculates an effective exchange rate based on real
exchange rate instead of nominal rate.
RER : Real Exchange Rate : It is the exchange rate which is based on constant prices to eliminate the effect of price changes.
Parity Value : In a fixed exchange rate system, the value of currency is fixed in terms of another
currency or in terms of gold.  This is known as parity value of currency.